Introduction
The postcommunist societies face, with respect to welfare provision,
three challenges. The first is that of the social costs of transformation.
"Under the twin impact of declining incomes and rising inequality, poverty has
risen dramatically in the transition economies," writes Branko Milanovic from
the World Bank (Milanovic, 1966, p. 175). The second challenge is the legacy of
the past: overextended, ineffective and inefficient institutions, and
inflated expectations. The postcommunist countries that are otherwise quite
advanced in making the transformation-Poland, Hungary, and the Czech
Republic-still have state-expenditure budgets that reach or exceed 50
percent of their GDP, and it is hard to imagine that the), can shoulder
such burden without paying heavy price in terms of economic efficiency
(Barbone and Polackova, 1966). The third challenge is the crisis of the
welfare state in the West, which eliminates for the transforming countries
any clear model for organizing their social safety net, except for one
piece of technocratic advice: reduce and downsize as much as possible
what you inherited from communist times.(1) Thus, the crisis of the
idea of the welfare state in the West has established one of the
important parameters of the market transformation in the East.
Two questions related to the problem of the social safety net in
Central Eastern Europe are of particular interest. The first, which
concerns the recent past, is, how to explain the relatively peaceful
acceptance of the disintegration, or--in some cases--near collapse
of existing institutions of social support in countries such as
Poland, Hungary, the Czech Republic, and some others as well.
"What is surprising," says Mark Kramer, "is not that hardships
emerged, but that the public reaction to them has been so tranquil"
(Kramer, 1996, p. 46). Contrary to many pessimist prophecies
formulated at the beginning of the transition, there were no
major upheavals, nascent democratic institutions were not threatened
(Greskovits, forthcoming, Ch. 1). The second question,
which concerns the present, is, why, even in those countries that
have made the most successful transformation to a market economy,
has the pace of reforms of the public services--of the "redistributive"
sector--been so much slower than that of the
"productive" parts of the economy, or that of the political and
legal spheres? "Reform of the welfare sector," says Janos Kornai,
"is the sphere of transformation where the least progress has
occurred. Indeed there has hardly been any change at all.... The
socialist system with all its well known features has survived in the
welfare sector" (Kornai, 1996).
In trying to sketch answers to these questions, I focus mostly
upon the experience of Poland, which as the first reforming
country has accumulated considerable experience. The Polish
economy is diversified, with a vibrant private sector on one hand,
and socialist industrial "dinosaurs" and stagnant agriculture on
the other. The ideological spectrum is vast, with an array of different
proposals and opinions offered. Finally, Poland has the
longest period of the resumption of growth of the countries
undergoing transition, and--as of now--is the only country, that
has attained their 1989 level of GDP (Commission for Europe,
1997, p. 225).
The most important points this paper makes are as follows: Historically,
the fact that the Polish society relatively calmly has
accepted the demise of the welfare arrangements of the socialist
times may be explained by three reasons: (1) the process of
decomposition has been relatively gradual and incomplete, (2)
the potential for political mobilization of groups particularly hard
hit has been relatively low, and (3) significant social groups have
supported the change. The slow process of readjustment of social
safety net institutions to new conditions, in turn, may also be
explained in two ways: (1) the incapacity of the intellectual and
political elite to formulate clear and attractive visions for the
reform of these institutions, and (2) the presence of forces within
the political economy that tend to preserve the status quo rather
than to press for new solutions. The argument may thus be
reduced to three main theses: (1) the change in welfare arrangements
is gradual and incomplete in nature; (2) the political and
intellectual elites are incapable of articulating programs; (3) a
balance of forces within the political economy contributes to the
inertia. The argument that I present here will follow these three
points, but for the sake of clarity, it is necessary to begin with a
frame of reference--with a short description of the welfare
arrangements under communism.
The Communist Welfare State
As historian Ivan Berend observes, "[s]ocial policy, the building
of a consistent social safety net and, given the economic standards
of the countries, a premature welfare system became prevalent
during the post-Stalinist decades" (Berend, 1996, p. 165). (The
term "premature welfare state" was coined by Janos Kornai
[1992].) The three pillars of the communist welfare state were
full employment, price controls combined with rationing, and
universal accessibility of such services as education and health
care, as well as the provision of pensions, sick pay, child care benefits,
maternity leaves, and so on.
The promise of full employment, that is, the right to a job provided
by the state, not only gave access to the means of survival,
but also served as a tool of social control, and work was treated as
much as a right as it was a duty. Those who did not work were
treated as parasites, or even as criminals. The workplace served as
much as a production unit as it served as a channel of access to
scarce goods and services. Prices and wages were set administratively,
and basic commodities (food, housing) were subsidized.
Rationing, in open or disguised forms, served two different ends:
allowing access to basic but scarce commodities to all who
(according to the authorities) needed them, and enabling the
authorities to use scarce goods of a more luxurious character as
rewards for political loyalty. Finally, pensions, education and
health care, but also various kinds of more specific benefits, were
provided by centralized, bureaucratic state machinery. Protection
was standardized and its distribution centralized, social insurance
integrated into the state budget, medical care provided by universal
health care service and separated from social insurance
(Voirin, 1993, p. 28).
Perhaps the easiest way to characterize the communist welfare
state is to contrast it with its Western counterpart- Comparing
them, we see superficial similarities hiding profound differences.
in each case, there were transfers of income, as there were institutions
of health care, education, child care, family programs,
housing policies, employment policies, state organized pension
schemes, and so on (one clear difference is that in the communist
countries, there were neither unemployment benefit programs,
nor antipoverty measures, as ideologically the existence of both
were denied). Despite those apparent similarities, there were,
however, profound differences. They may be summarized by saying
that in the West the institutions of the welfare state, having a
wide variety of ideological sources (Barr, 1987, pp. 9-68; Esping-Andersen,
1990), emerged and evolved historically in the long
process of piecemeal adjustments of social arrangements to tensions
produced by markets, which, however, remained the principal
mechanism of social coordination, while in the East these
institutions were designed as a part of a complete project of the
social system, under which the market was to be banned, and
imposed upon Eastern European countries according to the
model developed in the Soviet Union in the 1930s (Voirin, 1993,
p. 28).
From a political point of view, Western societies remained liberal.
Institutions of social protection were open to criticism,
adjustment, and redesign. Indeed, the present critique of the
deficiencies of the welfare state may be treated as part of such a
process of constant readjustment (Hirschman, 1982). As such, the
social order has been treated as flexible and open to constant
modifications. In the East, the social system--including welfare
provision--was treated as close to perfect and not subject to critique;
at the most only the particularities of implementation
could be questioned.
In the West, the distinction between different spheres of life--particularly
economic and political, but also private and public--has
been relatively clear. Separate institutions and different rules
of the game have governed each of these spheres, although they
have obviously overlapped and interacted. In the East, such distinctions
did not exist. All institutions were politicized. Enterprises,
or--better to say--workplaces, served as much to produce
goods and services as to provide political control, and were the
centers of distribution of goods and services to the employees.
Life under communism had thus a corporatist character (Chirot,
1980). Economic decisions were motivated by political goals, as all
spheres of life were politicized, while at the same time the public
had no say about the social order. The welfare system had a character
of bureaucratic paternalism, and citizens were treated as
irresponsible children.
The Western welfare state is often criticized for its tendency to
develop a "dependency syndrome" among its clients. Sociologists,
analyzing the communist system, stress that the same tendency
showed up in the East, but with much more intensity, producing
a universal syndrome of "learned helplessness," and making it
particularly difficult for people to adjust to situations in which
they had to take responsibility for their lives (Narojek, 1991; Marody,
1991).
It is because of these profound differences that it is so difficult
to reform the welfare system in the East, to retain what is good
and reject what is bad. Rather, a complete reconstruction would
be advisable, but that is impossible, since for practical reasons the
change must be piecemeal and gradual.
Change and Demise
The Eastern welfare state itself, as well as the perception of it by
society, evolved. With the passage of time, it came to be perceived
as unfair, inadequate, ineffective, and inefficient. This stemmed
in part from the rising consumer and cultural aspirations of the
public, especially the middle classes, exposed to the ways of the
West. What might have been attractive for peasants-turned-workers
during the industrialization of the 1950s was much less so for
professionals of the 1970s or 1980s. The dissatisfaction was also
caused by over-extension of services, resulting in poor quality, and
by bad management. Waiting lines were growing longer, bribes
were becoming universal, and whoever could afford it exited the
system, preferring services offered by the parallel economy. All
this discredited the communist welfare state well before the
regime finally collapsed. This disillusionment is worth remembering
when one wonders why it was so easy for many to forget the
cozy and safe world of real socialism. It is also worth realizing that,
since the crisis first started at the end of the 1970s (1978 was the
peak year of output, and since then it has decreased), the collective
memory of almost a full generation is that of socialism crippled
and malfunctioning.
Understanding the true nature of the disintegration requires
qualification. Its effects were noticed on the "real" rather than the
financial side of the communist welfare state. Until the end, the
level of expenditure, or its share in the budget, remained
unchanged. What really mattered, however, was the poor delivery
of services, caused by inefficiencies, mismanagement, and--since
the end of the 1970s--the general effects of prolonged economic
crisis. Of importance, therefore, is not so much the sheer deterioration
of the welfare system (long lines at the doctor's office
door, crowded classrooms, and so on), as the fact that it had
become increasingly discredited.
The next chapter in the evolution, which came after 1989, had
quite a bizarre character. By this point, of the three pillars mentioned
at the beginning of the preceding section, the first two had
almost disappeared, while the third one had remained almost
intact. What had left was all the factors that had that stemmed
from the promise of job security and the role of the workplace as
a channel for access to goods and services. In the newly established
private enterprises, in the enterprises that were privatized,
and even in many of those that remained in the public hands but
had to meet market demands, management was forced to relate
pay to performance, to get rid of holiday resorts and nurseries,
and to shed the redundant employees.
In Poland, the initial effects of the demise of this part of the
communist welfare state, however, were cushioned by the lavish
unemployment benefits (later to be curtailed), by early retirement
plans, and by the indexing of pensions. The same trend has
appeared in all eastern European countries, with the share of
social expenditure in the GDP rising. In Poland, it went up from
20 percent of GDP in 1990 to over 29 percent in 1994 (Golinowska,
1995, p. 30). In such a way, part of the welfare burden was
shifted from the enterprises to the public budget. The demise was
far from complete for yet another reason. Some large state enterprises
had managed, and still manage, to secure disguised government
subsidies, allowing them to retain employment that
otherwise would have to go. These policies display poor economic
judgment, but they act as a buffer against possible social frustration
and unrest. In a way, the case of agriculture is similar. Protective
tariffs, lax tax policies, and subsidies disguised in the form
of cheap credits are helping farmers to cope. Most of them would
hardly be able to compete if the markets were to be completely
deregulated, which is not surprising, taking into consideration
that Polish agriculture still employs 25 percent of the nation's
active labor force, in most cases in small, underinvested farms. To
be fair, it must be admitted that the new challenges of unemployment
and rising poverty have resulted also in a lot of innovative
behavior, particularly in the field of social assistance, and in the
sphere of labor retraining and job creation, where public authorities,
as well as nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) have
become quite active (Bledowski, 1996)
Another part of the former system to go was subsidization of
food prices, which covered 30 percent of the value of food consumption
in 1988 (Graham, 1994, p. 222). The tremendous
increase in food prices, which came at the turn of the 1990s and
brought them close to European levels, hit the low-income categories
of population particularly hard and caused a rapid increase
in the number of those living below the poverty line. However, the
control of the cost of energy ameliorated the hardships connected
with the steep rise in the cost of living.
Public services, of which health care and education are the
most important examples, is a totally different story. Here, the
basic institutions, as established under the communist system,
have remained almost unchanged to this day. It is true, however,
that they suffered from budget slashes, occasioned by new budgetary
discipline. This has led to the curtailing of various services,
a dramatic lag in wages in relation to other sectors of the economy,
and the strengthening of corrupt practices in the form of
under-the-counter payments, as well as the semilegal privatization
of some services, in particular in the health care sector.
Pensions were the exception. The political strength of pensioners,
as well as the subsequent governments fear of unemployment,
resulted in indexing and in early retirement plans. As a
result, pensioners' position relative to wage-earners improved.
The cost was that the state pension fund developed significant
deficits, as the shrinking of the labor force and the reluctance of
troubled enterprises to pay their due contributions made it hard for the
funds to meet the increased obligations. Deficits had to be covered by the
public budget, which became one of the most important dangers for state
finances. The problems were made even more painful because of the greater
reluctance of farmers to contribute to the separate farmers' pension fund,
and to the subsequent inability of government to curtail the special
pension privileges of certain groups, such as the army, the police,
miners, and teachers.
To sum up the process of evolution, or rather the process of
disintegration, of the former system of welfare provision, we may repeat
that it has been gradual and incomplete. Thus, people had enough time to
learn the newly emerging rules of the game and to adjust their personal
life strategies in a step-by-step way--perhaps reducing the danger of
violent social reactions. Looking on this evolution, one also notices that
for the most part it has had a spontaneous character, resulting from the
overall market changes and anti-inflationary polices, little has been done
to reform welfare provisions according to some clear design. "No political
party has taken on serious reform of the social welfare system as a
platform issue," wrote an American analyst about the situation up to 1993
(Graham, 1994, p. 212). A Polish expert observes that, "within the last
few years no political discussions that could lead to coordination of main
principles of health care system functioning were conducted in Poland"
(Tymowska, 1996, p. 25). What happened is mostly a change by default.
This is in striking contrast to other sectors of economy, where reforms
were much farther reaching, as well as in contrast to radical reforms of
the political sphere.
Ideology
One of the reasons for the slow pace of the reforms of the public
services sector was the lack among the Polish intellectual and political
elite of a clear program, or vision, of how this sector should be
organized, save for the vision of economic liberals.(2) This might appear
strange, taking into consideration the traditional leftist bias of the
Polish intelligentsia on one hand, and the high value attached to
religious values on the other.
Social-democratic sympathies preceded World War II, were
widespread before the Stalinist turn in 1949, and were present
after the liberalization of 1956. Democratic revisionists inside the
party and economists believing in market socialism put their
hopes in an evolution of the Soviet-type regime into a more
acceptable form. The successes of the Keynesian intervention in
the West, and that of the Western European welfare state, supported
views (also quite common in the West) that in the long
run, communism and capitalism would converge into a new form
social organization, combining market, state, and democracy. A
social-democratic orientation was also common among intellectuals
serving as advisors to Solidarity in 1980-81, and later during
the 1989 Round Table talks. This line of thinking is still being
continued by the noncommunist social democrats (politically,
represented by the Labor Union), closely resembling the Western
European social democracy of the past and advocating a mixed
economy, employee ownership and participation in management,
and a substantial role for the state in providing welfare. Lacking a
clear message from Western social democracy, they seem unable,
however, to propose solutions that would somehow come to terms
with the negative experiences of the Western European welfare
state, and they have not done very much to translate their ideas
into an operational form with feasible, practical solutions.
The former-communists-turned-social-democrats, in power
since 1993 until at least the moment this paper is being written
(summer 1997), seem not to bother with articulating the theoretical
underpinnings of their views and attitudes. Those economists
who are close to them in their writings are not far from mainstream,
liberal opinion, stressing the importance of correct
macroeconomic policies, although they might put more faith in
state intervention.
On the other side of the spectrum, various segments of the self-styled
Polish right, stressing national and sometimes also religious
values, seem unable to go beyond populist demands for protection
of family, labor, and national economy. In contrast to economic
liberals, they are long on catchy slogans, but short on
substance and argument. Strikingly, in the deeply religious Polish
society, with a powerful church and with sympathies to the Pope,
who is so outspoken on social questions, there is no modern,
Christian Democratic orientation of the kind that pushed for
social reforms in some Western European countries, particularly
in Germany.
All this leaves the economic liberalism as the dominant intellectual
current. To the surprise of Western observers, who usually
see the sources of liberlism's popularity in Western advisors, there
have been indigenous roots for liberal ideology--particularly
what Jerzy Szacki calls "economic liberalism," to make it distinct
from political liberalism, which for historical reasons he finds in
short supply in Central Eastern Europe (Szacki, 1995, pp.
119-70). Groups of young liberals emerged in the late 1970s and
early 1980s, for whom the only way out of communism was to
build, on the grass-roots level, the attitudes of economic
entrepreneurship, as they believed that political change without
proper economic foundations would fail. These groups have had
a wide appeal among students, who read samizdat copies of works
of Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman. Economic liberalism
also found its way to Poland via professional economists, who
gradually became disillusioned as to the feasibility of market
socialism.
External influences were also important in forming economic
liberalism, but through a wider avenue than just the technical
advice given by foreign experts. On theoretical grounds, neoclassical
economic analysis and its developments--including the anti-Keynesian,
monetarist trend, as well as theories of public choice
and of "government failure"--have been followed by academics,
who have had easy access to the West since the 1960s. Ambitious
graduate students were eager to follow this line of thinking well
before 1989, and after this date mainstream economics also
became widely taught to the undergraduates in the more ambitious
economics departments. More practical influence came
from the critics of the Western European welfare state, who
pointed at cracks in its structure due to the combined weight of
global competition, demographic change, inflated expectations,
and the rising dependency of its clients (Rosenvallon, 1981; ISSA,
1995). A young Eastern European intellectual's perception of
Western welfare state thus changed, from that of seeing it as a
great invention, allowing Western societies to combine market
efficiency with social security and humane decency, into an inefficient
monster, causing inflation, producing dependency, stifling
initiative, and endangering civil liberties.
Since the beginning of the transformation, young economists
found themselves in the role of educators of the public in the
matters of organizing economic and social systems. Their beliefs
were reinforced by evident successes of market-oriented reforms
in less developed countries, particularly in Latin America, of
which Chile was the example most often cited. Their credibility
ensured by Western mainstream economics, and their resolve was
supported by the backing of the powerful international institutions,
particularly the World Bank. The majority of Polish economic
liberals are not libertarians and they do not oppose state
involvement in welfare organization, but they would like to see
the state in a regulatory role rather than as a direct provider, and
as for the use of public resources, they would like to see it done
within budgetary prescriptions, in an efficient and effective way.
According to their views, the central government and its bureaucracy
should play a subsidiary role, stepping in only when individual
citizens, firms, nongovernmental organizations, and local
governments fail. By and large, it can be said that an idealized
vision of the American system is closer to the hearts of economic
liberals than the European model, both in its state-centered and
corporatist versions (for comparisons, see Esping-Andersen, 1990,
pp. 26-27; Esping-Andersen and Micklewright, 1991).
While in general terms the message of economic liberals has
been well articulated, much less has been done to translate it into
a concrete reform of social security. Welfare provision has not
been at the center of their attention; rather, they have concentrated
on how to reform the overall institutional framework of the
economy, focusing on enterprises and the financial sector in particular.
As for the welfare state, only a general message was clear:
it should be downsized as far as is politically feasible, and restructured
considerably. Economic liberals find the present state of
affairs unacceptable, as the overextended state is incapable of
providing quality services, and the high incidence of taxation and
high costs of labor stifle economic initiative. They advocate such
initiatives as: a change in the pension system, from pay-as-you-go
to funding; the introduction of health insurance; turning government
schools and clinics over to local governments, to the NGOs,
or to the private sector; introducing educational vouchers; and
targeting benefits to the really needy. Most of these ideas still only
exist in a general form, although some have been translated into
practical proposals. Two projects are worth mentioning as particularly
well elaborated: one proposing pension reform and one for
higher education financing. The first (now being pushed through
the parliament) has been put together by an ad hoc expert team
under the umbrella of the Ministry of Labor and backed by the
World Bank (BP, 1996). The second is a detailed proposal for
introducing tuition, combined with students loans, into the public
institutions of higher education, and was prepared by an independent
think tank (Woznicki, 1997).
The strength of economic liberals, relative to those of other
orientations, is their ability to put ideas into an operational form,
through creation and financing of several think tanks. It is proper
to make a remark here that perhaps is all too obvious, namely that
the question of translating general ideas into workable projects of
institutional "piecemeal social engineering," to use famous Popper's
notion, is not a trivial matter. It requires more than sheer
enthusiasm--it usually needs months of detailed, painstaking
work by teams of specialists (whose work, incidentally, does not
come cheap), particularly economists and legal experts. The ability
to put such teams together and to finance them is evidently in
short supply. Because of the ideological climate prevalent in the
West, it is easier to find money and other forms of support for
projects closer to ideas of economic liberalism than other
options.
While economic liberals have well articulated and coherent
views, they have trouble, however, with marketing and selling
these views to the wider public, which somehow does not seem
eager to accept cold, logical arguments of economic rationality.
This is a result of not only their lack of persuasion, but also of the
balance of political forces.
The Political Economy
What is the nature of the game insofar as the institutions and
policies related to welfare provision are concerned? It is difficult
to say without a slightly wider look at the attitudes toward the
whole process of market transformation.
There is no doubt that transformation, particularly at the early
stage, is brought about with tremendous social costs (Graham,
1994; Milanovic, 1996; Golinowska, 1966; Andorka, 1977; Ferge.
1977). This fact, however, did not provoke political reactions
strong enough to block the reform process. During the initial
period of "shock therapy" (when prices were freed, subsidies cut
down, and wages in the state sector kept low in order to hold
down inflation) the lack of protest was due to the "extraordinary
politics," when the new, freely elected government enjoyed a
credit of trust, enabling it to push through very radical reforms
(Balcerowicz, 1995). Additionally, as I have noted before, considerable
measures were taken to protect the most vulnerable--unemployed
and pensioners. When the period of extraordinary
politics ended--somewhere in mid-1992--indeed, mobilization
against reforms showed up in the form of a series of strikes (Graham,
1994, pp. 193-95). Former-communists-turned-social-democrats
capitalized upon these sentiments and won the
parliamentary elections of 1993. However, after their victory, they
did not change the course radically, but pursued the same policies
that economic liberals did--especially insofar as macrostabilization
is concerned--although on a slowed pace. (I shall return
in a moment for reasons why did they do so.)
After the former communists gained power, the nationalist,
anti-Communist right became vocal in using popular sentiments
against supposedly unjust economic policies, combining that with
rhetoric targeted against the ruling coalition. The right did not
attack capitalism as such, but rather what they perceived as a parasitic
form that capitalism took due to alleged manipulation of
the former communists, who were interested solely in enriching
themselves, and due to the operations of foreign capital. The
right--which consists of the Solidarity trade union and an assortment
of smaller and bigger parties, often at odds one with
another--has shown, however, surprisingly little capacity for concerted,
unified action, and apparently is unable to present a clear
and convincing political program. The populist, demagogic, but
also ineffective politics of the right is, incidentally, often a matter
of concern for more intellectually oriented conservative writers
and columnists.
A much more balanced position is presented by the noncommunist
social democrats, represented by the Labor Union. Their
problem, however, is how to construct their identity in such a way
as to stress differences between themselves and the social democracy
of the former communists. Since the latter pursue centrist
policies, maneuvering between the desire to maintain the process
of market transformation and the wish not to alienate those parts
of their electorate that are hostile to radical reforms, the Labor
Union is pushed to the left (in the traditional sense of the word:
more state, more redistribution), with considerable problems in
keeping its electorate.
Market transition has not only enemies, but friends as well,
particularly among the young and the better educated, and their
numbers have been growing with time (Adamski, 1993; see also
Graham, 1994, pp. 209-10). The increase in the number of small and
medium-size businesses in Poland proves that substantial segments
of society have adjusted well to the new situation, showing
that pessimist prophecies, voiced at the beginning of transformation,
were wrong. "While giving lip service to capitalism and radical
economic reform, the vast majority of the Polish people are
hooked on socialism and are not likely to change anytime soon,"
stated a Western author in 1991 (Naylor, 1991). Contrary to such
opinions, many Poles proved to be well trained for the new reality.
Much of their learning came well before the final collapse of
the system, during the long process of the exit from communism,
when those disillusioned with the statist economy engaged in all
kinds of private activity, often within the framework of parallel
economy. At present, a small but telling proof of the popularity of
the market economy is the booming of private business schools.
Leaving aside the dubious quality of the education that some of
them offer, the demand for their services shows that for the
important segment of the young generation, business and the
market are being seen as the keys to personal success in the
future.
Members of the former communist elite also have a keen interest
in keeping on the road to capitalism. Many younger, more
ambitious, and more enlightened members of the former nomenklatura
found emerging capitalism to their advantage, building
"political capitalism," or turning political capital into economic
capital, and securing for themselves managerial positions, and, if
possible, property (Staniszkis, 1991, pp. 38-69; Szelenyi 1995,
p. 190). This is why this group, which holds key position in government
since 1993, may be slowing down the pace of reforms to
accommodate dissatisfied groups of their political clients (particularly
the large, postcommunist unions), but is not interested in
changing the direction.
The ruling coalition, however, is apparently less eager to push for drastic
reforms of the welfare arrangements. The reasons are not so much ideological
as practical, stemming from the logic of situation. Pushing through
monumental changes would be difficult for any government, since they are not
particularly popular. Economic soundness calls for reduction of the share of
budgetary transfers in the GDP. That would mean reducing subsidies for ailing
industries, which still command significant political leverage; abolition of
certain acquired rights; curtailing of money benefits; narrowing the range of
services provided by the state; and the introduction of users' fees. Not
surprisingly, it is not easy to sell such a program politically. It would be
attractive to the middle class only, who would expect higher quality and easier
availability of services--and lower taxes as well. The middle class, however,
even if supportive of the reforms, are neither numerous nor easy to mobilize,
and their members prefer the individual exit options of tax evasion and private
provision of services over collective action for the change of institutions and
policies.
The reforms would also call for the managerial streamlining of the
institutions that provide such services as education and health care, or even
more far-reaching institutional redesign, such as turning some of them over to
the local governments (which has actually been done in certain measure with
schools) or to NGOs. The status of some of their employees would be changed
from that of civil service to contract employment. Such changes are perceived
as endangering vested interests. "The bureaucracy that runs the state and
semi-state, corporatist welfare sector, fearing erosion of its power, resists
all reforms that point towards decentralization, competition and the market"
(Kornai, 1966). Two examples may serve as an illustration: one is
education, the second is health care.
The educational system is under criticism, as--according to the opinion of a
leading expert in the younger generation, the late sociologist
Wertenstein-Zulawski--"it does not teach initiative . . . but passivity and
lack of responsibility for one's future. The young
most often leave schools badly educated, unprepared for life and
for the adult world. Not surprisingly, they end up as unemployed"
(Wertenstein-Zulawski 1993). Critics call for changes in the methods and
content of education, as well as better preparation of
teachers, but with little result. One reform idea (advocated by the
World Bank and some other international organizations) is to
reduce the number of teachers, to increase the teaching load, to
introduce the system of promotion of teachers based on merit--and
to increase pay, which now is hopelessly low and attracts only
mediocre and poor candidates to the profession. The hope is to
achieve both an increase in quality, and a rise of efficiency. Such
proposals have been, however, fiercely opposed by the teachers'
union, which is closely associated with the former communists.
The teachers' opposition stems not only from their reluctance to
lose some jobs, but also out of fear of a more meritocratic system.
As things stand now, low pay and low obligations are preferred to
more demanding solutions, despite the hope of a higher reward.
In the public health care system, reforms are opposed by lobbies
of highly placed bosses of Poland's clinics and hospital wards.
The existing system allows them to realize high incomes through
private practice, often executed on the premises of public health
care institutions. Since they control access to the patients of public
medical facilities, which are in short supply I not surprisingly
they do not lack private patients. As for the lower-level medical
personnel, such as nurses, they also find accommodation within
the existing system due to private, untaxed payments from
patients searching for better care.
In both cases, the monopoly of ill-functioning and partly corrupt
state institutions is only slightly affected by the emerging private
sector, which mostly serves the more affluent members of
society. It also remains to be seen whether this arising competition
would improve the public sector, or rather lead to the abandonment
of the push for improvement called for by the more
vocal members of society, preferring "exit" to "voice" (Hirschman,
1970). While the service providers are well organized to block any
changes, clients (students, parents, and patients) are much less
focused, unable to organize, and not eager to press for reforms.
Their private strategies, in case of emergency, are to search to
establish personal relationships with a service provider. Moreover,
lower-income recipients are less interested in the quality of services
than the cost and would probably oppose either copayments
or narrowing down the range of services and shifting some of
them to the private sector.
One exception, where things seem likely to move, is pension
reform (BP, 1996). The long-term plan calls for replacing the present
pay-as-you-go system with a three-pillar system, where one pillar
consists of small basic pension guaranteed by the state, the
second pillar is obligatory but funded (and organized in the form
of pension plans within the framework of the enterprise), and the
third is private insurance. The eagerness to go on with the pension
reform is explained by two reasons. One is that the present
state of affairs is painful from any governmental point of view,
since on one hand the state has a legal obligation to pay due pensions,
and on the other it has tremendous trouble with raising the
necessary contributions. Even though reform would not solve the
present problems (it would bring visible results only after two
decades), at least there is a psychological readiness to proceed.
The second reason is that, contrary to the examples of health and
education sectors, pension reform is, at present, hardly dangerous
for any social group. However, that is due to the fact that the
suggested reform does not go so far as to curtail special pension
privileges of certain groups (teachers, miners, the army, and the
police), which cost the state budget dearly. Two political parties of
pensioners have registered to participate in the upcoming elections,
so it remains to be seen whether opposition to this pension
reform will arise.
Instead of Conclusions
The sheer power of the market transformation destroyed much
of the communist welfare state. Little, however, was reformed with
purpose, as the forces of the political economy and the lack of
thoughtful reform proposals resulted in the preservation of the
status quo. Paradoxically, Polish society's tendency to halt
reforms, whether honest or stemming from political opportunism,
might have reduced the social costs of transformation,
and prevented dangerous upheavals. The status quo, however,
would be hurtful to maintain further because it is too costly, and
because the quality of services is too low.
The future of welfare provision in Poland, as well as in the
other, more successful postcommunist countries, is not clear, as it
is not clear in the West. For Ralf Dahrendorf, maintaining social
cohesion in the face of global competitiveness is squaring the circle
(Dahrendorf, 1995-96). The crisis of the welfare state is as
much an economic and political problem as it is a reflection of a
deeper identity crisis in this era of globalization. Historically, the
welfare state was an attempt to create institutions of social
solidarity--institutions that replaced functions fulfilled in preindustrial
times by the family and the local community--based on
national identity (Kochanowicz, 1966). With national solidarity
eroding in the face of global challenge, the emotional, moral, and
ideological foundations of the welfare state have also been cracking,
under their own weight. While it is hard to deny the problems
the welfare state faces at the moment, one should be wary of writing
off its experience too easily. If we agree that, historically, it was
an answer to tensions and dislocations produced by the market,
industrialization, and technological change, an answer that tried
to respond to the longing for a modicum of security and some
form of solidarity and connection between of individuals and the
society, than we must admit that it did not fare that bad, as compared
with two other solutions that the twentieth century
brought: fascism and communism. Its successes stem from the
fact that the Western welfare state has been liberal and democratic,
and it has not been hostile to market capitalism. This success
is part and parcel of liberal society's ability to scrutinize its
institutions and to reform and readjust them constantly.
The situation of Eastern European countries is more problematic
than that of the West, as they are poorer, while the relative
size of the welfare sector they inherited from communism is
larger. They also lack the liberal democratic tradition of solving
social problems through debate and piecemeal readjustments.
The particular danger facing these countries is twofold. On the
one hand, maintaining structures that are overextended, ineffective,
and inefficient stifles economic growth. On the other, too
radical reduction of welfare provisions easily may lead to the
emergence of a self-reproducing, socially marginalized underclass,
which the United States knows all too well and which, due
to permanent unemployment, is quickly on the rise in Western
Europe (The Economist, 1994). To make things even more complicated,
switching to programs that treat their clients as passive
recipients, instead of empowering and enabling them, may also
lead to the creation of an underclass. There are signs that such a
class is already taking shape in Central Eastern Europe. The segment
of the younger generation that happens to live in areas hard
hit by unemployment (often the industrial centers of the communist
era) and is unprivileged regarding the access to education
are particularly endangered.
Enabling and empowering, indeed, should be the guiding principles
of welfare provision (Sen, 1995), but it is easier said than
done. If enabling and empowering is to serve as a standard, then
there is still a long way to go for Poland. Education and investment
in human capital in general seem to be the most neglected,
if judged by the attention they get from politicians and their
constantly diminishing share in the public budget. The expenditure
on education decreased in real terms, from 1989 to 1993, by 30
percent (Golinowska, 1995, p. 31). Nobody lobbies for education,
while many do so for ailing agriculture and outdated industries.
The only clear vision of what to do about welfare provision
comes from economic liberals. What they suggest is probably
sound and correct, although the details are obviously always
debatable--as is the idea of targeted assistance, for example (Sen,
1995)--but it is a vision that many are wary to accept. The logic
of economic soundness so often finds itself at odds with the logic
of mass democracy. As Stanley Hoffman has recently observed,
commenting on the developments in France, "the French workers
and middle classes are reluctant to dismantle a welfare state
that was fought for over decades ... and to which they owe a
degree of well-being and security that is, in many ways, a progressive
and humane achievement" (Hoffman, 1997, p. 48). Democracy
gives people the ability to search for ways of making their life
more stable and secure, something the work of market forces
does not allow, and it would be a mistake to believe that they
would easily renounce this commodity. That does not mean that
it is hopeless to expect the possibility that welfare institutions will
be rationalized, or even reduced. Such an agenda, however,
requires painstaking efforts by the political and intellectual elite
to explain the necessity of these changes, to negotiate them, to
convince the public they are necessary--and to engage people in
active reshaping of the institutions that are vital to them.
Notes
(1) I am using the term welfare state in its broad, comprehensive meaning,
which is closer to the European usage than to the American way of
understanding welfare as assistance to certain needy groups.
(2) I am using the term liberal, when related to the economy, in the
European sense of favoring the free market, not in the American sense
of favoring intervention and redistribution.
References
Adamski, Wladyslaw, "Zroznicowanie postaw i interesow wobec prywatyzacji
i kapitalu zagranicznego, [Differences of interests and
attitudes related to the privatization and foreign capital] in:
Andrzej Rychard and Michal Fedorowicz, eds., Spoleczenstwo w transformcji
[Society in transformation] (Warsaw: MS PAN, 1993).
Andorka, Rudolf, "The Development of Poverty During the Transformation
in Hungary," in: Ivan T. Berend, ed., Long-Term Structural
Changes in Transforming Central & Eastern Europe (The 1990s)
(Munchen: Sudosteuropa-Gesselchaft, 1997).
Balcerowicz, Leszek, Socialism, Capitalism, Transformation
(Budapest-London-New York: Central European University Press, 1995).
Barbone, Luca and Hana Polackova, "Public Fiances and Economic
Transition," Studies and Analyses 69 (Warsaw: Center for Social and
Economic Research, 1966).
Barr, Nicholas, The Economics of the We4fare State (London: Weinfeld and
Nicholson, 1987).
Berend, Ivan, Central and Eastern Europe 1944-1993: Detour from Periphery
to the Periphery (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).
Bledowski, Piotr, "Rola administracji publicznej w funkcjonowaniu
pomocy spolecznej" [Public administration role in social assistance],
in Stanislawa Golinowska, ed., Polska bieda. Kryteria. Ocena.
Przeciwdzialanie [Poverty in Poland. Criteria. Evaluation. Alleviation]
(Warsaw: IPiSS, 1966).
BP (Biuro Pelnomocnika Rzadu d/s Reformy Zabezpieczenia
Spolecznego [Office of The Plenipotentiary of the Government for
Social Safety]), Bezpieczenstwo dzieki roznorodnosci. Reforma systemu
emerytalnego w Polsce (Security thorough difference: The reform of
the pension system in Poland] (Warsaw, 1991: mimeo).
Chirot, Daniel, "The Corporatist Model and Socialism," Theory and
Society 9:2 (1980).
Dahrendorf, Ralf, "Squaring the Circle: Competitiveness and Social
Cohesion in Free Societies," Newsletter, Institute for the Human
Sciences, Vienna, no. 52 (December 1995-February 1996).
Economic Commission for Europe, Economic Survey of Europe in
1996-1997 (New York and Geneva: United Nations Economic
Commission for Europe, 1997).
Esping-Andersen, Gosta, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990).
Esping-Andersen, Gosta and John Micklerwight, "Welfare State Models
in OECD Countries: An Analysis for the Debate in Central and
Eastern Europe," in Giovanni Andrea Corinne and Sandor Sipos, eds.,
Children and the Transition to the Market Economy (Aldershot: Averbury, 1991).
Ferge, Zsuza, "Is the World Falling Apart? A View form the East of
Europe," in Ivan T. Berend, ed., Long-Term Structural Changes in
Transforming Central and Eastern Europe (The 1990s) (Munchen:
Sudosteuropa-Gesselchaft, 1997).
Golinowska, Stanislawa, "Polityka spoleczna panstwa" [Public social
policy], Przeglad Spoleczny 27-28 (1995).
Golinowska, Stanislawa, ed., Polska bieda, Kryteria, ocena, Przeciwdzialanie
[Poverty in Poland, Criteria, Evaluation, Alleviation] (Warsaw:
IPiSS, 1966).
Graham, Carol, Safety Nets, Politics, and the Poor. The Transitions to
Market Economies (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1994).
Greskovits, Bela, The Political Economy of Protest and Patience: East
European and Latin American Transformation Compared (Budapest: Central
European University Press, forthcoming).
Hirschman, Albert O., Shifting Involvements: Private Interests and Public
Action (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1982).
Hirschman, Albert O., Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms,
Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press, 1970).
Hoffman, Stanley, "Look Back in Anger," The New Fork Review of Books,
July 17, 1997.
ISSA (International Social Security Association), Social Security Tomorrow:
Permanence and Change (Geneva: International Social Security Association,
1996).
Kochanowicz, Jacek, "New Solidarities:, Market Change and Social Cohesion
in a Historical Perspective," in Ivan T. Berend ed.. Long-term
Structural Changes in Transforming Central and Eastern Europe (The
1990s) (Munchen: Sudosteuropa-Gesselchaft, 1997).
Kornai, Janos, The Socialist System: The Political Economy of Communism
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1992).
Kornai, Janos, "Reform of the Welfare Sector in the Post-Socialist Countries:
A Normative Approach," paper presented at the Workshop on
Economic Transformation and the Reform of the State, National
Research Council, Washington, D.C., November 8-9,1996, mimeo.
Kramer, Mark, "Social Protection Policies and Safety Nets in East-Central
Europe: Dilemmas of the Post-Communist Transformation," in
Ethan B. Kapstein and Michael Mandelbaum, eds., Sustaining the
Transition: The Social Safety Nets in Postcommunist Europe (New York:
Council on Foreign Relations).
Marody, Mira, (ed.), Co nam zostalo z tych lat ... Spoleczenstwo polskie
u progu transformacji systemowej [What are we left with ... Polish
society at the threshold of systemic change] (London: Aneks,
1991).
Milanovic, Branko, "Income, Inequality and Poverty during the
Transition," Research Policy Research Department of the World Bank
Transition Economies Division Project, Research Paper Series, no. 11 (March
1966).
Narojek, Winicjusz, Socjalistyczne "Welfare State" [Socialist welfare state]
(Warsaw: PWN, 1991).
Naylor, Thomas H. [rev. of] Daniel Chirot, ed., "The Origins of
Backwardness in Eastern Europe," Contemporary Sociology, 20:1 (1991).
Rosenvallon, Pierre, Le crise de l'Etat-providence (Paris: Seuil, 1981).
Sen, Amartya, "The Political Economy of Targeting," in Dominique van de
Walle and Kimberly Nead, eds., Public Spending and the Poor. Theory and
Evidence (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995).
Staniszkis, Jadwiga, The Dynamics of the Breakthrough in Eastern Europe. The
Polish Experience (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1991).
Szacki, Jerzy, Liberalism after Communism (Budapest: Central European
University Press, 1995).
Szelenyi, Ivan, "Wnioski" [Conclusions], in Ivan Szelenyi, Don Treiman
and Edmund Wnuk-Lipinski, eds., Elity w Polsce, w Rosji i na
Wegrzech. Wymiana czy reprodukcja? [Elites in Poland, Russia and
Hungary: Circulation or reproduction?] (Warsaw: ISSP PAN, 1995).
The economist, "Europe and the Underclass," The Economist, July 30,
1994.
Tymowska, Katarzyna, "Main Directions of Changes in the Health Care
System in Poland," in Katarzyna Tymowska, Vanessa Malin, and
Andy Alszewski, eds., The Contracting System in the Health Sector in
England and Poland (Warsaw: Olympus, 1996).
Voirin, Michel, "Social Security in Central and Eastern Europe:
Continuity and Change," International Social Security Review 46:1 (1993).
Wertenstein-Zulawski, Jerzy, "Niepokoj w skansenie" [Uneasiness in a
Skansen museum], Gazeta Wyborcza, August 14-15, 1993.
Woznicki, Jerzy, ed., Wspolplatnosc za studia dzienne [Co-payments for
higher education] (Warsaw: Instytut Spraw Publicznych, 1997).
(*) I wish to express my deep thanks to Irena Topinska for
information she agreed to share with me and for her extremely
valuable and pertinent comments.
COPYRIGHT 1997 New School for Social Research
COPYRIGHT 2004 Gale Group